我想不起曾有哪一個(gè)時(shí)刻,市場(chǎng)預(yù)期美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)會(huì)做的事跟美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)自己預(yù)計(jì)要做的事差異如此巨大。市場(chǎng)預(yù)計(jì)美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)到2017年底會(huì)將利率提高到1.6%,而聯(lián)邦公開(kāi)市場(chǎng)委員會(huì)(FOMC)的平均預(yù)計(jì)值為3.5%。
Such a divergence raises the risk of volatility and poses a communications challenge for theFed. More important, it raises the question of what should guide future policy.
這種認(rèn)知差異會(huì)帶來(lái)市場(chǎng)波動(dòng)風(fēng)險(xiǎn),也讓美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)在向市場(chǎng)傳遞信息方面遇到挑戰(zhàn)。更重要的是,它引發(fā)了應(yīng)以什么來(lái)指導(dǎo)未來(lái)政策的問(wèn)題。
Especially after Friday’s very strong employment report, there can be no doubt that cyclicalconditions are normalising. The unemployment rate now is at its postwar average level, andcontinues to fall. Job openings are above their historic average. Other indicators such as theinsured unemployment rate suggest a normal or rapidly normalising economy. All of thistaken in isolation would suggest that interest rates should not remain at zero much longer.
特別是最近強(qiáng)勁的就業(yè)報(bào)告出爐之后,周期性狀況正在恢復(fù)正常這一點(diǎn)已不再有疑問(wèn)。眼下失業(yè)率處于戰(zhàn)后平均水平,并在繼續(xù)下降。職位空缺數(shù)量超過(guò)歷史平均值。參保失業(yè)率(IUR)等其他指標(biāo)顯示,經(jīng)濟(jì)已回歸正軌、或正迅速回歸正軌。只從這些來(lái)看,說(shuō)明零利率不應(yīng)維持太長(zhǎng)時(shí)間了。
On the other hand, the available inflation data suggests little cause for concern. The coreconsumer price index has averaged 1.1 per cent over the past six months; if housing costswere stripped out it would be zero. Wages actually fell in December and over the past yearemployment costs have risen 2.25 per cent which, in conjunction with productivity growth ofonly 1 per cent, suggests inflation of below 2 per cent. Perhaps most troubling: marketindications suggest inflation is more likely to fall than rise .
另一方面,現(xiàn)有通脹數(shù)據(jù)表明沒(méi)有什么可擔(dān)心的。核心消費(fèi)價(jià)格指數(shù)(CPI)過(guò)去6個(gè)月的均值為1.1%,如果剔除住房成本,則核心CPI為0。去年12月工資實(shí)際上下跌了;過(guò)去一年的雇傭成本上漲了2.25%,而生產(chǎn)率僅增長(zhǎng)了1%,這意味著通脹率不到2%。最令人不安的或許是:各項(xiàng)市場(chǎng)指標(biāo)顯示通脹率降低的可能性大于升高的可能性。
The Fed has rightly made clear that its decisions will be data dependent. The further key pointis that it should allow the flow of information on inflation rather than on real economic activityto determine its timing in adjusting interest rates. And it should not raise rates until there isclear evidence that inflation, and inflation expectations, are in danger of exceeding its 2 percent target. Here are four important reasons why.
美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)明確表示有關(guān)調(diào)息的決定將取決于數(shù)據(jù),這是對(duì)的。更關(guān)鍵的一點(diǎn)是,它應(yīng)根據(jù)有關(guān)通脹、而不是實(shí)體經(jīng)濟(jì)活動(dòng)的數(shù)據(jù)決定何時(shí)調(diào)息,并且不應(yīng)在有明確證據(jù)顯示通脹、以及通脹預(yù)期有可能超過(guò)2%目標(biāo)值之前升息。這么說(shuō)有四個(gè)重要理由:
First, real wages for most workers have been stagnant. Median family incomes are down by 4.5per cent over the past five years and the economy is about $1.5tn — or $20,000 for theaverage family of four — below pre-recession estimates of its 2015 potential.
首先,大多數(shù)勞動(dòng)者的實(shí)際工資一直停滯不前。過(guò)去5年家庭收入中值下降了4.5%,目前的經(jīng)濟(jì)規(guī)模比衰退前預(yù)測(cè)的2015年潛在經(jīng)濟(jì)規(guī)模低出約1.5萬(wàn)億美元,相當(dāng)于每個(gè)家庭(按平均每家4口人計(jì)算)低于預(yù)測(cè)值2萬(wàn)美元。
In such circumstances efforts to reduce demand and growth require a compellingjustification. Yet the idea that below normal unemployment will necessarily lead toaccelerating inflation as suggested by the so called Phillips curve is very uncertain. Contraryto such predictions, inflation did not decelerate by much even a few years ago whenunemployment was in the range of 10 per cent. Nor was there much evidence ofaccelerating inflation in the 1990s when the unemployment rate fell below 4 per cent.
在這種情況下,若要采取降低需求和抑制增長(zhǎng)的措施,需有充分理由。然而,所謂的菲利普斯曲線(Phillipscurve)所描繪的情形——低于通常水平的失業(yè)率肯定會(huì)導(dǎo)致通脹加速上升——存在極大不確定性。與菲利普斯曲線預(yù)測(cè)的情形相反,就在幾年前,當(dāng)失業(yè)率達(dá)到10%水平的時(shí)候,通脹也并沒(méi)有降多少,而上世紀(jì)90年代,失業(yè)率降至4%以下時(shí),也沒(méi)有多少證據(jù)顯示通脹升高。
Second, if inflation were to accelerate a bit this would be a good thing. It is now running andis expected to run below the Fed target. Prices are about 4 per cent below where they wouldhave been if 2 per cent inflation had been maintained since 2007. So there is a case for someinflation above 2 per cent to catch up to the Fed’s price level target path. They may also be acase for inflation a little bit above 2 per cent for the next few years to allow real interest rateslow enough to promote recovery when the next recession comes.
其次,假如通脹真的略有升高,那是件好事。眼下通脹率低于美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)目標(biāo)值,并且預(yù)計(jì)未來(lái)將繼續(xù)低于目標(biāo)值。假如通脹自2007年至今一直維持2%,那么物價(jià)水平將比現(xiàn)在高4%左右。因此,讓通脹升至略高于2%是有理由的,這樣可以讓物價(jià)水平追趕美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)的目標(biāo)物價(jià)水平??紤]到目前的物價(jià)水平低于目標(biāo)水平,讓通脹在未來(lái)幾年維持在略高于2%還能夠讓實(shí)際利率變得足夠低,以便在下一次衰退到來(lái)時(shí)為推動(dòng)復(fù)蘇提供空間。
Third, a plane that accelerates too rapidly as it takes off may cause passengers discomfortwhile a plane that accelerates too slowly may crash at the end of the runway. Historicalexperience is that inflation accelerates only slowly so the costs of an overshoot on inflationare small and reversible with standard tightening policies. In contrast, aborting recovery andrisking a further slowing of inflation is potentially catastrophic — as Japan’s experiencedemonstrates. So in a world where economic forecasts are highly uncertain, prudence inavoiding the largest risks counsels in favour of Fed restraint in raising rates.
第三,飛機(jī)起飛時(shí)加速太快會(huì)讓乘客感到不適,但起飛太慢,飛機(jī)可能會(huì)墜毀在跑道上。歷史經(jīng)驗(yàn)顯示,通脹升高速度并不快,因此通脹超標(biāo)的成本很小,并且可通過(guò)實(shí)施常規(guī)緊縮政策來(lái)補(bǔ)救。相反,讓復(fù)蘇中斷、冒讓通脹進(jìn)一步放緩的風(fēng)險(xiǎn)卻可能造成災(zāi)難性后果——如日本的經(jīng)驗(yàn)所示。因此,在這個(gè)經(jīng)濟(jì)預(yù)測(cè)高度不確定的世界里,出于避免最大風(fēng)險(xiǎn)的審慎考慮,美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)應(yīng)謹(jǐn)慎對(duì)待升息。
Fourth, the US has never been more intertwined with the global economy. Higher interest ratesand the stronger dollar they would bring would mean greater debt burdens for debtorcountries, a growing US trade deficit that damages manufacturing, and growing protectionistpressures.
第四,美國(guó)與全球經(jīng)濟(jì)的聯(lián)系從未像現(xiàn)在這樣緊密。更高的利率、以及高息帶來(lái)的更強(qiáng)勢(shì)美元,意味著債務(wù)國(guó)的債務(wù)負(fù)擔(dān)將變得更重,美國(guó)貿(mào)易赤字會(huì)增加(不利于制造業(yè)),貿(mào)易保護(hù)主義壓力也會(huì)增強(qiáng)。
There is already a danger given all the problems in Europe, Japan and emerging markets thatsafe haven flows will drive the dollar up to the point where the US economy could besignificantly slowed. Raising rates without evidence of rising inflation could dramaticallyincrease real rates and exacerbate these risks.
鑒于歐洲、日本和新興市場(chǎng)的種種問(wèn)題,目前已經(jīng)存在這樣的風(fēng)險(xiǎn):因資金流入避險(xiǎn)貨幣,導(dǎo)致美元幣值升高到可能使美國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)顯著放緩的地步。在沒(méi)有證據(jù)顯示通脹升高的情況下升息,可能使實(shí)際利率大幅上升,加劇上述風(fēng)險(xiǎn)。
None of this is to say that rates should never be raised or that inflation indicators might notjustify a rate increase before long. It is to say that the Fed could inject much neededconfidence in the economy today and minimise future risks by announcing and following astrategy of not raising rates until it sees the whites of inflation’s eyes.
這些并不意味著我們應(yīng)無(wú)限期推遲升息,也不意味著通脹指標(biāo)不可能在短期內(nèi)變得支持升息,而只是說(shuō),通過(guò)宣布和遵循這樣一種策略——“在沒(méi)有看到通脹的確鑿證據(jù)之前不升息”,美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)可使人們對(duì)經(jīng)濟(jì)重拾信心(這是當(dāng)前非常需要的),并最大程度地減小未來(lái)的風(fēng)險(xiǎn)。
The writer is Charles W Eliot university professor at Harvard and a former US Treasurysecretary
本文作者為哈佛大學(xué)(Harvard)查爾斯•W•艾略特大學(xué)教授(Charles W Eliot University Professor),曾任美國(guó)財(cái)政部長(zhǎng)